India Today |
AT the end of the
nineteenth century, Oscar
Wilde in his famous play The Importance
of being Earnest had talked of the precipitous fall in
the value of the
Indian rupee. Well over a century later alas, the Indian
rupee is still
falling, its latest fall as precipitous as any in Oscar
Wilde’s time. On July
12, 2011, the exchange rate was 44 rupees to a US dollar; by
end-June 2013, it
has plummeted to 60 rupees per US dollar, a 27 percent
decline in two years.
The government has
attributed this decline to
the fact that Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the US Federal
Reserve Board,
announced on May 22nd that an end was in sight to the Fed’s
policy of
quantitative easing, ie, the policy of keeping down US
interest rates by injecting
liquidity into the system. Bernanke’s announcement made
speculators shift funds
to the US where the interest rates are expected to rise, and
this has reduced
the value of all other currencies, including the Indian
rupee (and even of
gold), vis-a-vis the US dollar. The government therefore
claims that what is
happening to the rupee is happening to other currencies as
well, so that there
is nothing specifically to worry about. Sooner or later the
“markets” will
settle down.
UNTENABLE EXPLANATION
This explanation
however is patently untenable.
True, in the wake of Bernanke’s announcement the dollar has
appreciated
vis-a-vis other currencies; but, as already mentioned, the
rupee has been
falling for quite some time vis-a-vis the dollar, long
before Bernanke’s
announcement. Besides, the rupee has depreciated vis-a-vis
not just the dollar
but vis-a-vis all major currencies, which means that even
though Bernanke’s
announcement might have had an additional effect on the
rupee, as on other
currencies, the basic problem underlying the depreciation of
the rupee is quite
different. What is this problem?
It is this
incidentally which constitutes the
fundamental argument against opening up the economies of the
periphery to free
capital flows: with such freedom, the movement over time, no
doubt through
fluctuations, will be for funds to flow out from the
periphery. And this means
that there is a secular tendency for the exchange rate of
peripheral economies
to decline in a world of free capital flows, which would
ultimately mean that
the wealth of the periphery will pass into the hands of
wealth-holders from the
centre who hold the strong currency of the centre. Not that
this happens
suddenly; there is however an undeniable tendency towards
this, which manifests
itself sporadically, but in a pronounced fashion, followed
again by long
periods when the peripheral currency does not depreciate,
and everybody begins
to think that no such asymmetry ever characterised the world
economy.
Now, it so happens
that the nineties of the last
century and the early years of the present, ie, precisely
the period when India
started its neo-liberal policies, were periods of boom in
the metropolis,
especially in the US, because of a series of “bubbles”,
first the “dot-com
bubble” and then the “housing bubble”. True, this boom was
not as pronounced as
the post-war boom that is often referred to as the “Golden
Age of Capitalism”:
in fact if we split the entire post-war period into two, one
spanning 1950-73
and the other spanning 1980-2008, leaving out the crisis
years of the
mid-seventies, we find that the GDP growth rate for the
advanced capitalist
world in the latter period was distinctly lower than in the
former. The point
however is that nonetheless there was a boom, no matter
whether as big as the
earlier one, in the nineties of the last century and the
first decade of the
current one. Because of the exuberance associated with this
boom, there was
also a flow of finance to the so-called newly emerging
economies of the
periphery which were opening up to capital flows for the
first time since
decolonisation. This put an upward pressure on the
currencies of these
countries, which was checked only by their Central Banks
holding on to large
reserves of foreign exchange. All this
created the illusion that these economies were as good as
the centre in terms
of the “confidence of the investors”, that they had ceased
to be considered
peripheral economies by globalised finance capital, that
they would continue to
attract funds from the centre, and that their currencies
were no longer subject
to any secular tendency towards depreciation. And in India
this
illusion was particularly strong because the boom years of
metropolitan
capitalism coincided exactly with its journey into
neo-liberalism. The crisis
in the centre however has put an end to all these illusions.
TRAVAILS OF THE RUPEE
In the current
travails of the rupee, there are
no doubt India-specific factors which explain why the Indian
rupee is doing
even worse than other similarly-placed currencies; but these
India-specific
factors are superimposed upon a basic structural
characteristic of the world
economy, which explains for instance why the US dollar
continues to remain
strong despite the US persistently running a massive current
account deficit
but the Indian rupee collapses in the face of a large
current account deficit.
The rupee cannot be
allowed to depreciate
continuously as it is doing now. Every such depreciation
increases the costs of
imports, especially of oil, which, under the current regime
of
automatic-pass-through to the ultimate consumers, entails an
inflationary
burden on the people. In fact this burden is implicitly
assumed by the
government when it expresses the belief that the markets
will ultimately
“stabilise”. In economists’ jargon this burden is one of the “stabilising” or “equilibrating”
factors.
To see this imagine
a simple world which
produces one single commodity using an imported current
input (oil), and
labour, applied to capital stock. The price of the product,
as is usual in
oligopolistic markets, is a mark-up over the sum of the
current input cost and
the labour cost per unit of output. Now suppose the current
input cost rises by
10 percent because of currency depreciation, then, with a
given mark-up, if
real wages remain unchanged, then the
price level will also rise by 10 percent. The nominal
depreciation of
currency by 10 percent, accompanied by a price rise of 10
percent, will mean
that the real effective exchange rate remains unchanged, ie,
the economy gets
back to square one, where the same
factors that had caused the initial depreciation would
cause a further
depreciation; and so on ad infinitum. It is only
because real wages are not
expected to remain unchanged that anyone would at all
believe that some new
“equilibrium” will be reached where the economy will settle
down.
Now, this simple
picture of the economy can be
made more complicated but that will not affect the basic
conclusion, whence it
follows that the
government is actually
banking on a real wage decline, ie, an erosion of the real
living standards of
the working people via inflation, to bring the economy to
an equilibrium, where
a further decline in currency value will not occur. This
assumption must be
resisted for its own sake, even as it stands, since the
living conditions of
the working people cannot be made hostage to the whims of
finance capital.
Besides, it is also a dangerous assumption, since there is
no determinate limit
to the degree to which the living standards of the working
people will be
pushed down in this manner.
Underlying the government’s inaction therefore there is something else, namely a belief that the world economy itself is going to turn around fairly soon, which means that the basic crisis that had caused this trouble for the rupee would itself disappear. This assumption however has no basis. And because of this, the Indian economy is entering a period of acute crisis. The people’s resistance in the face of this crisis, as during the 1930s when they rose against colonialism, will inaugurate a new phase of Indian history.
No comments:
Post a Comment